This is backward. I am posting two pieces here: The first one is a comment that appeared below the second one, the actual article. The article is pretty intellectual, but has some really good ideas in it. I'll try to highlight of couple of them for those of you who don't want to slog through the whole article (or just read the subtitles). the article is a great analysis, but offers no solution (once again....). The comment talks about a means to a solution, and a person who devised and instituted that solution.
Actually, if you read the article, I suggest reading the comments too -- they're mostly really good -- it's a good discussion without much name-calling. There are a couple of comments that suggest a book to read, which I am thinking of getting --it sounded good.
Find it here:
http://truth-out.org/opinion/item/24489-the-compelling-conclusion-about-capitalism-that-piketty-resists --Kim
parrysixte
11 hours ago Under way since before 1992 in Detroit
"The Next American Revolution," Grace Lee Boggs
Bill Moyers:
http://billmoyers.com/content/... Wikipedia,
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/G... Democracy Now
http://www.democracynow.org/ap... Grace Lee Boggs, Detroit-based radical organizer and philosopher. Born to Chinese immigrant parents in 1915 [in their apartment over the family's restaurant], Now 99, she has been involved in every major activist movement of the past eighty years, including labor, civil rights, black power, women's rights, and environmental justice movements. She has been at the forefront of efforts to rebuild urban communities. Theoretician as well as activist she has come to profoundly reconstruct the very conceptions of system change and "revolution."
She earned scholarships and graduated from Barnard, went on to earn a PhD in Philosophy at Bryn Mawr in 1940.. Facing the significant employment barriers in the academic world as a woman of color in the 1940s, she took a job at low wages at the University of Chicago Philosophy Library, living in a rat-infested basement . She began there her career as theoretician and activist...working for tenants' rights,
Along the way she met and married Jimmy Boggs, a Black from the deep South, for 30 years a union worker and organizer in the Chrysler factory in Detroit. Theoreticians as well as activists, they were deeply immersed in the passionate discussions about revolutionary doctrine which characterized leftish organizations. [They found the Communist/USSR perspectives profoundly wrong, working with C.L.R James in the Johnsonite anti-stalinist perspective .]
From all of this they emerged with a radically different perspective: they saw that thinking about revolution had come to be centered on a process of rousing the masses to take over existing systems at the top and from there to rework the structure to be more supportive for the people generally [according to whatever structure the proponents advocated].
They proposed to do something quite different: to reconceive what "revolution" was about; and to rebuild societies' entire structures from the ground up.
They had come to see that "The courage, commitment and strategies required
for this new kind of revolution would be very different from those required to storm the Winter Palace or the White House. Instead of viewing the U.S. people as masses to be mobilized in increasingly aggressive struggles for higher wages, better jobs, or guaranteed health care ...
"...we must have the courage to challenge ourselves to engage in activities that build a new and better world by improving the physical, psychological, political and spiritual health of ourselves, our families, our communities, our cities, our world, our planet."
This was not just abstract thinking; it grew directly out of eighty years of on-the-picket lines action; and having reconceived what 'revolution' was in theory they went on to action.In 1992; they, with Shea Howell, and others, co-founded "Detroit Summer," which intended to "rebuild, redefine and respirit Detroit from the ground up," beginning by organizing youth.
They had come to embrace Martin Luther King's vision of the "beloved community;" they called on Detroiters to expand their humanity, to work together to create a more humane, democratic, and meaningful way of life, not just in Detroit but in line with the thinking eg underlying the work of the World Social Forum on the theme "Another World Is Possible," central to the Puerto Alegre forum of 1999 and to participatory government
..." we need to go beyond opposition, beyond rebellion, beyond resistance, beyond civic resurrection. We don't want to be like 'them.' We don't want to become the 'political class,' to simply change presidents and switch governments.
"We want and need to create the alternative world that is now both possible and necessary. We want and need to exercise power, not take it."
She set forth these views in a book: "The Next American Revolution," Univ California press, 2011. [see also her autobiography, "Living for change,"
Univ Minnesota, 1998.]
For me a most important thing about this view is not just its thorough, careful exposition - though imo this is indeed revolutionary - but that, having reinterpreted the history and having worked out the theory the Boggses and friends put the theory into action.
Beginning specifically and actively along these linesin 1992; she, with Jimmy Boggs, Shea Howell, and others, co-founded "Detroit Summer," intending to "rebuild, redefine and respirit Detroit from the ground up," beginning by organizing youth.
Over time Detroit Summer has developed parallel and interrelated activities loosely linked: Arts, Media, Culture; Community Organizations; Education [Schools and Community]; Food Security - Urban Gardens and Farms; restorative justice, Local Businesses: Sustainable Economics; Recycling; Youth & Activism.
Some specifics...
Activities in general aim to strengthen the community as well as to overcome specific challenges..Murals turn depressing deteriorating walls into images celebrating a vibrant locality.
A Restorative justice movement replaces arrest and incarceration in cases of many crimes; this keeps juveniles out of the criminal justice system; and it resolves conflicts in the community without the toxicities of the "justice" system.
Children are not locked into rows of desks in sterile classrooms; reminded,
under the evils of teach to the test that they are chronic failures; they are given activities and places in the community where they can both learn and
feel the satisfaction of knowing that their work has value and that they
themselves are productive parts of the community.
For instance, one group undertook to study their community to see where there were needs for improvement..In due course they identified youth obesity as a community problem...but they didn't stop there, they went on to create vegetable gardens, some on rooftops, to improve sources of healthy foods...[*]
And this leads on to A major theme in the ongoing work in Detroit; the evolution of the 'beloved community' sketched out by MLK. With people engaged in 'Work;' not regimented in 'Jobs;' with communities oriented to neighborhoods not "projects," with humanized schooling, with community oriented restorative justice... with communities finding ways to provide supporting services.. They will approach King's vision the "beloved community
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
The Compelling Conclusion About Capitalism That Piketty Resists
Thursday, 26 June 2014 00:00 By
Fred Guerin,
Truthout | Op-Ed
Temporary, like sadness. Temporary, like capitalism. Temporary, like life. (Photo:
Dominic Alves / Flickr)
Want to help publish more stories like this one? Truthout is powered by reader support - click here to make a tax-deductible donation now!
The excesses of capitalism are not simply a question of bad management and a political unwillingness to properly regulate it by imposing the right sort of checks and balances, but symptoms of a fundamentally and irretrievably flawed system that tends toward destruction of human and other life.
The idea of capitalism as an expression of economic freedom that also secures moral and political
freedom of thought, or the notion that "free-market" economies are guided by an impartial mechanism of supply and demand - an "invisible hand" to use Adam Smith's metaphor - are both powerful indoctrinating notions. As such, they bear little resemblance to actual reality. Smith himself never used the word "capitalism," preferring to call his economics a "system of natural liberty." In fact, the inner logic of capitalism can be difficult to get hold of simply because there have been different configurations of capitalism throughout history. In its classic form, before the advent of corporations (when there was still an implicit sense of social responsibility, and insatiable greed was considered a vice), capitalism might have appeared less virulent. Additionally, there is reason to believe that capitalism unfolded differently in different countries with distinct political and legal frameworks.
"There is "capitalism" and then there is "really existing capitalism." What then is 'really existing capitalism?'"
All of these contingent factors are worthy of consideration in any assessment of capitalism. However, it is also reasonably clear that once we actually look at history, it is difficult not to conclude that pretty much
every embodiment of capitalism - classical capitalism, oligarchic or corporate capitalism, casino capitalism, entrepreneurial capitalism - presuppose similar elements: private property, ownership of the means of production, notions of unlimited growth, the maximization of profit, using wealth to create wealth. They also all embody a form of instrumental rationality, the kind of rationality concerned with maximizing profits and minimizing costs. In its globalized corporate form, capitalism has been able to relentlessly realize this form of instrumental reasoning on a large scale - and thereby show itself as one of the most destructive and undemocratic economic system humans have ever come up with.
Unfortunately, neither propaganda nor abstract economic theory can help us to grasp this fact. The reason is primarily that the latter do not really speak to the false theories of human nature capitalism presupposes. Nor do many of them elaborate capitalism's legitimating normative-moral or political origins. Most crucially, they are often silent regarding the devastating impact that it has had on the environment since it first emerged during the course of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. As Chomsky insightfully puts it, "There is "capitalism" and then there is
"really existing capitalism." What then is "really existing capitalism'?
Thomas Piketty's
Capital in the Twenty-First Century gives us a few clues, though not by any means, the whole picture. Replete with startling empirical evidence in the form of charts, graphs, informative statistics, mathematical-logical expressions and astute critical-historical analyses, Piketty's work draws a number of sobering conclusions about the present dynamics of wealth and income distribution that exposes not merely the dark underside of capitalism but a central contradiction within it. Thus, Piketty concludes ". . . wealth accumulated in the past grows more rapidly than output and wages. This inequality expresses a fundamental logical contradiction. The entrepreneur inevitably tends to become a rentier, more and more dominant over those who own nothing but their labor. Once constituted, capital reproduces itself faster than output increases.
The past devours the future."
The past
devours the future. But, what if the bizarre inverted logic of capitalism has always been its real point? What if, under the rubric of capitalism, the powerful elite are given permission to act as if it simply doesn't matter whether their ever-expanding wealth might actually devour the future, or "wear the world out faster" to borrow a phrase from Orwell? Do they not often appear to live in an all-consuming present - get what you can for yourself right now, and don't worry about others, or even about tomorrow? Moreover, is not such an attitude, sanctioned by capitalism, the reason why this particular economic system requires endless cycles of economic crisis?
Perhaps Piketty's point is that if it doesn't matter to the elite, it should at least matter to us. But if it
does matter, then it is up to the rest of us - including experts like Piketty who grasp the reality of capitalism better than anyone else - to imagine real alternatives to such an economic system, to think outside of the present paradigm of endless development, profit maximization and disastrous austerity measures imposed on whole populations. Despite the apparently glaring "logical" contradiction within capitalism, Piketty
still holds to the idea that it can be properly disciplined through a progressive annual tax on wealth. It is not the conclusion he should have reached given his thorough and prescient analysis.
Looking at the history of capitalism, it is difficult not to conclude that growing inequality expresses a fundamental property of and not a contradiction within capitalism.
Of course, Piketty is by no means alone in wanting to save capitalism from itself. Capitalism - no matter what its excesses, or how destructive it is for life or democracy - is invariably held as our default economic system, grudgingly acceded to even by popular left-oriented economists such as Paul Krugman, Nouriel Roubini or Joseph Stiglitz. As Chrystia Freeland unabashedly concludes in
Plutocrats, The Rise of the New Global Super-Rich and the Fall of Everyone Else, despite all its faults, we continue to need capitalism because, "very much like democracy," it is "the best system we've figured out so far." [
1] Thus, if capitalism appears to go wrong, this is not because it is grounded on a misreading of history, internal contradictions, false theories about nature or human nature, or misguided moral and political presuppositions. Rather, the excesses of capitalism are simply a question of "bad management' and a political unwillingness to properly regulate it by imposing the right sort of checks and balances.
In fact, Piketty's proposed wealth tax solution may do more to obscure than resolve the really existing contradictions of capitalism. Looking at the history of capitalism, it is difficult not to conclude that growing inequality expresses a fundamental property
of and not a contradiction
within capitalism. Inequality is built into capitalism. If there is a contradiction here it is a material not a logical one. In other words, it is the contradiction between an economic system that is radically indifferent to the health and well-being of the planet as a whole versus the economic, moral and environmental obligation to preserve and sustain such health and well-being.
If I am right that the inner logic of capitalism inevitably leads to a hegemonic, macro-structural world-system of unequal human social, political and economic relations guided by elite greed that does not reflect the best interests of the majority of people, the common good or indeed the good of the planet itself, then Piketty's assumption that we could ever regain control over an "endless inegalitarian spiral' by imposing a progressive tax on capital seems, is at best, rather fanciful. A more fitting conclusion in the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis and the efforts of the elite to profit from the latter would be to ask the question whether we should continue advocating for a capitalist system that glorifies profit over people or start thinking about how to reorganize our economy around common goods such as the health and well-being of our present world.
Instead, many contemporary economists repeatedly tell us that our only tenable alternative is to tame capitalist excess through regulative initiatives. This has been done before and it can be done again, the argument goes. Thus, it is claimed that we can and did rein-in or mitigate the severity of capitalist exploitation, and the massive wealth and income disparities that followed from it. However, it should now be abundantly clear that the internal and structural logic of exploitation, wealth-income disparities and the profit-oriented colonization of social and political relations can only be regulated for short periods. It can never be fundamentally altered. Indeed, as Piketty has persuasively argued, relentless exploitation, colonization and massive inequality were only temporarily pre-empted by a war economy and FDR's regulatory initiatives. By the late 1970's, the internal logic of capitalism had re-established its hegemonic status and all of the built-in excesses of the capitalist economic system once again became normalized and necessary.
What if . . . we are all conditioned to see the world in terms of individual economic self-interest rather than in terms of common human good or planetary limits, health and equilibrium?
What this tells us is that regulatory reform of capitalism will only be allowed for a brief period. In other words, to the extent that it can obscure or prevent us from perceiving the inner logic of a system of structured inequality, or distract us from the most deleterious effects of capitalism on the environment and on human health and well-being, minimal regulation may be deemed necessary by the elite for a short period of time. However, as
Naomi Klein has convincingly argued, the "collective vertigo' caused by wars, economic upheaval, environmental or political crisis, environmental disasters can also be exploited as the perfect means through which a capitalist system of greed takes over markets, amasses fabulous fortunes and bankrupts the wealth of the commons.
Perhaps the refusal to ask critical questions about the viability of capitalism might be explained by the fact that even today many economists still hold onto the mythic assumption that the "impartial" self-regulating market is no more than a theoretical expression of the "order of human nature" itself and not, after all, a product of powerful political and moneyed interests. This belief has distant origins in Thomas Hobbes fear-inspired mechanistic account of human beings who in their natural state are war-like and driven by self-interest. Not only does the latter perspective resonate in many manifestations of capitalist theory, it also underscores a desire to replicate in economic theory what nature apparently prescribes - a war-like disposition disciplined through competitive markets based on innate selfishness. But what if the incapacity to imagine alternatives is not because we are naturally selfish, but simply a function of the reality that in capitalist societies we are
all conditioned to see the world in terms of individual economic self-interest rather than in terms of common human good or planetary limits, health and equilibrium?
This perfectly predictable inversion, where government becomes a handmaid to moneyed interest, is precisely the "logic of a capitalist system."
Over time, the promotion of selfishness as a virtue not only changes the way we look at ourselves, it influences the way we relate to each other and to the planet itself. Instead of citizens who define themselves in relation to common goods, we are reduced, under the selfish orientation of capitalism, to aggregates of self-interested atomistic individuals encouraged to believe that we can continue a lifetime of limitless consumption. Those who are entirely left out of the consumer game - the increasing numbers of homeless, stateless refugees, destitute and imprisoned whose day-to-day life is taken up by the fight for mere survival - are the necessary residue of a global capitalist system.
From its inception, capitalist economic theory has pushed the idea that the market would only be able to regulate itself if it were not subject to external and coercive government interference or regulation. However, the reality is that capitalist accumulation was
never actually severed from politics or government, but invariably parasitic upon it. It has
always been intimately tied to publicly funded government tax-breaks and subsidies, to war, colonial-imperial expansion, and industrial ambitions. What happened is simply that massive capitalist accumulation was allowed to entirely invert the power relation between moneyed interests and government. Thus, an elite class of bankers, financiers and industrialists (eventually expressing itself through corporate ownership) have become so powerful, they are able to coerce governments and states to go along with whatever is in their minority interest. This perfectly predictable inversion, where government becomes a handmaid to moneyed interest, is precisely the "logic of a capitalist system," which renders any suggestion of government imposed progressive taxation rather fantastical.
Related to this, faith in the promise of capitalism might also have to do with a kind of wilful blindness about the actual origins of capital. As Karl Polyanyi reminds us, many scholars and economists tenaciously hold to Adam Smith's idea that the division of labor has
always been based upon markets of some kind because our "propensity to barter, truck and exchange one thing for another" is simply
ingrained in the natural order of things. But, clearly we do not need capitalism - the privatizing of wealth and the socializing of costs - to show us how to barter, truck or trade goods. Indeed, capitalism is actually inimical to bartering or trading, precisely because it is driven by individual profit and monopolization, not by the fair exchange of goods. The FTA (Free Trade Agreements), NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement) and TPP (Trans-Pacific Partnership) are the awful modern exemplars here.
There is nothing impartial about early capitalism's inextricable relation to colonialism, slavery or plunder for private gain.
Polyani quickly dispels Smith's historical misreading of the division of labor as structured by capitalism by reminding us that up to Smith's time such a propensity toward the individual pursuit of unfettered profit based on wage labor "had hardly shown up on a considerable scale in the life of any observed community and had remained, at best, a subordinate feature of economic life . . . "[
2]. The historical and anthropological evidence clearly suggests that it was not until the industrial age that the capitalist-inspired "wealth of nations" was realized by a hegemonic economic system guided by self-interested priorities and the exploitation of material goods and human beings in a relentless pursuit of profit for the few. Before this period, our economics were oriented by social, community, tribal and familial concerns that were considered far more important than the private possession and accumulation of goods based wholly on economic self-interest.
A more precise and broad-based historical study would conclude that, in point of fact, there isn't anything
in nature, the human condition, morality or history that necessitates the adoption of capitalism. It would also disclose that there is nothing
impartial about early capitalism's inextricable relation to colonialism, slavery or plunder for private gain. In point of fact, the historical reality is that market capitalism is intimately tied to a colonial-imperialist political agenda. This imperialist history clearly demonstrates that there is also very little that is "free" about a "free-market" that derives its freedom to accumulate wealth by way of slave labor, slave wages, debt bondage, unjust land confiscation and the expropriation of common lands and resources into private hands. In America, the so-called "free market" wedded private self-interested exploitation of labor with imperialist state interest on a scale that dramatically dwarfed the brutality of old-world Europe. It should not be in the least surprising then that the slave plantation might capture the essence of our modern global capitalist system, insofar as it is built on the premise of extracting maximum labor at minimal cost.
Of course when one looks at history, it is not immediately apparent that the "founding fathers' of capitalism - John Locke, Adam Smith, David Ricardo - wanted to intentionally construct a system that would entrench massive inequality. The latter figures were highly articulate, systematic, future-oriented thinkers who believed that private property, free trade, competition and laissez-faire capitalism were inherently good, and had an unlimited potential to raise the
general welfare of society. However, even here, those who enjoyed the fruits of a capitalist political economy were relatively few - certainly not the working class or slaves. Each of these illustrious thinkers exemplifies in his writings the material contradictions that capitalism represents.
To be fair, from the perspective of the 18th and 19th centuries, the planet did appear to have unlimited potential for growth, not to mention individual and social enrichment.
Moreover, the science of pollution and toxicity of industrial chemicals 200 years ago was nowhere near the advanced state it is now. However, the material contradictions of capitalism are starkly illustrated even in its earliest philosophical foundations. Thus,
on the one hand, John Locke's (1632-1704) political philosophy begins (as against Hobbes') with the idea that in our "original state of nature," we are not in a state of war, but in a state of " 'perfect freedom' to order our action, and dispose of our possessions and persons, as we think fit, within the bounds of the law of nature, without asking leave, or depending upon the will of any other man." This state of nature, Locke believed, is also a state ". . . of equality, wherein all the power and jurisdiction is reciprocal, no one having more than another." [
3]
However,
on the other hand, not all people were heir to such "perfect freedom" in their "natural state" or otherwise; nor did they have possessions or reciprocal power. In fact, a good many of them were not even treated as "persons" or individuals, but as mere "savages." There is nothing fair or equal about the fact that Locke's tremendous wealth was directly the result of investments in the silk and slave trade. Indeed, he believed that important, moneyed land barons should form "a government of slave-owners" and suggested that children over 3 years of age who were from families on relief should attend "working schools" so they would be "from infancy . . . inured to work"
[4]. Appearances notwithstanding, the "sacred and inviolable right to property" that Locke espouses is not something either slaves or the laboring classes were granted. The "perfect freedom" was indeed "perfect servitude" of those who were not white Europeans.
Behind the wonderful talk of liberal values, "increasing the common stock of man through money" and individual rights, Locke put forward an absolutist theory of property that would provide legitimacy to the imperialist ambitions of England and wealthy English landowners in America.
The problem is that Locke's morally grounded theory of the right to private property presupposes the expropriation of ancestral native lands, the existence of slavery and the impoverishment of laboring classes. As Ronald Wright has astutely noted, quoting from Senator Dawes in his Allotment Act, the problem with "Indians" is that they lacked "selfishness, which is the bottom of civilization"! [5] What we are compelled to conclude here is that these historical facts are not unpredictable events or anomalies of capitalism, but perspectives and practices intrinsic to the expansion of a capitalist economy.
The unavoidable question is why Smith advocated a "capitalist economic system" that glorified unbridled competition - a practice he intuited would inevitably corrupt our "natural sentiments" and deepen a proclivity toward selfish behaviour?
The Scottish Enlightenment thinker Adam Smith (1723-1790) believed that not only did competition mitigate the ruthlessness of self-interest, but the providential "invisible hand of the market" would ensure that in promoting our self-interest we would be simultaneously promoting the interests of society, whether we intended to do so or not. But, the rational or enlightened self-interest of Smith's economic man breaks down fairly quickly within the logic of monopolistic capitalism. Smith, like Piketty, is prescient enough to caution about the monopolistic trajectory of capitalism and the potential that industry and business had for influencing politics in their favour over the good of consumers and society as a whole. Moreover, against the logic of unfettered capitalist accumulation, he also thought laborers should be well paid and the rich and indolent taxed for the benefit of the poor.
At the same time, Smith's "merchant" is not much different than the modern corporate CEO. A merchant he explains ". . . is not necessarily a citizen of any particular country. It is in a great measure indifferent to him from what place he carries on his trade; and a very trifling disgust will make him remove his capital, and together with it all the industry which it supports, from one country to another."
[6] It is not hard to imagine that the "trifling disgust" classical merchants or modern CEOs experience is a consequence of having unions or governments interfere with their profits by demanding workers receive a living wage.
In the end, the unavoidable question is why Smith advocated a "capitalist economic system" that glorified unbridled competition - a practice he intuited would inevitably corrupt our "natural sentiments" and deepen a proclivity toward selfish behaviour? If the answer is that it is the self-correcting, providential "invisible hand" that reconciles selfishness and the general welfare of society, then Smith's entire economic system rests on a fiction:
There just is no such thing as an "invisible hand," nor has there ever been any such providential or moral self-correcting mechanism within capitalist economics. Given this, it is difficult not to conclude that Smith (again, like Piketty)
did, in fact, fully grasp the adverse effects and inherent material contradictions of capitalism. Nevertheless, he held steadfastly to the idea that a phantasmal occult force (the invisible hand) would enable our natural sympathy with the plight of others and our natural self-interested expression of individual freedom to live peacefully together.
What is startling is not how different, but how
similar the speculative capitalist mindset has always been. The early 19th century economist, broker and speculator David Ricardo ". . . made the bulk of his fortune as a result of speculation on the outcome of the
Battle of Waterloo, using methods that today would result in prosecution for
insider trading and market manipulation ."
[7] It is not a great leap from insider trading (which Milton Friedman, much later, enthusiastically endorsed) to securities fraud, negligent subprime mortgage lending, unregulated credit default swaps and so on. But it is also evidently true that wealth
is power - power cashed out at the political level. Ricardo, who was able to use his largesse to buy a seat in the UK Parliament, would probably not have had any problem with the Supreme Court
Citizens United decision to remove limits on corporate political donations. Perhaps we have here one of the earliest exemplars of how moneyed interest, power and political ambition are easily woven together in a capitalist political economy. At any rate, it is clear that the very
visible hand of the elite class inevitably renders government "by and for the people' pretty much irrelevant - or better,
invisible.
As for economic theory,
Ricardo's assumption that with social progress, the price of labor is "dear when it is scarce and cheap when it is plentiful" might explain why today the superrich have "stopped worrying and learned to love unemployment and under-employment." As the rich have become even richer since the 2007 financial crisis, the global unemployment rate has steadily increased such that by 2015, 205 million people will be out of work - and this doesn't even touch those who have given up looking for a job. Of course, Ricardo, like Marx after him, was clever enough to recognize that the interests of wealthy landowners were often in direct opposition to the good of society and would inevitably create tension and upheaval. This did not, however, prevent him from advocating for the abolition of the Poor Law which, he believed, encouraged people to be lazy and irresponsible - "are there no prisons? . . . are there no workhouses?"
Despite some indications to the contrary, Hobbes' theory of human nature is unambiguously presupposed in Locke, Smith and Ricardo's elaboration of capitalist political economy. All are essentially in agreement with the idea that we are "by nature" selfish creatures. Perhaps it is only in this sense we can be said to be "equals" - we are all equally selfish.
However, such a presupposition, by any objective measure, is simply false. We know today, from abundant empirical, sociological, psychological, genetic, archaeological and anthropological evidence, that Hobbes' theory of human nature as intrinsically "selfish" is deeply flawed. We are not "naturally" selfish - though we can, indeed, learn to be so. In other words, within a capitalist system it can become trueover over the course of time that an elite few will be chiefly oriented by greed, narcissism or selfishness - and some of the latter not so very far from the "squeezing, wrenching, grasping, scraping, clutching, covetous old sinners!" Dickens describes Mr. "Scrooge" as in
A Christmas Carol. Of course, today the latter are no longer viewed as "sinners." The real problem is that in our present world they are the "glorified masters" of our economies and governments. They are continuously praised, deferred to, considered "above the laws of the land" and allowed to live in a world of unabashed opulence entirely walled off from the rabble of mankind. Succinctly put, in capitalism, the greedy of the world have discovered their ideal legitimating cover: the promotion of a self-serving economics that turns the vice of selfishness into the highest virtue human beings can realize!
[8] History aside, from our own contemporary perspective, we can get a sense of "really existing capitalism' by virtue of the following thought-experiment, which reveals the latter in its unadorned state. Imagine that we were able, right now, to ask the 7 or so billion people living on the planet whether they would choose an economic system that would inevitably lead to massive wealth and income inequalities, that would severely limit equal opportunity, that would force whole populations to live under perpetual economic austerity, that would erode any possibility of meaningful and democratic political participation, that would devastate the health of the planet and the human body while externalizing the costs of such destruction onto everyone, with the exception of a very privileged few.
Now . . . how many people do you think would actually opt for such an arrangement? Honest answer: Almost no one! The only people who would agree to such a set of conditions would be an infinitesimally small group whose present privileged economic status would be protected and furthered by maintaining the status quo. The fact is that though there are many manifestations of the capitalist system, the intentional logic of capitalism always was, and still is, the same: to protect and perpetuate the power, status and privilege of the few, while impoverishing everyone else.
Given this, you might think that we would seriously question anyone who asserts that capitalism best captures or reflects the essential capabilities, wants, desires or needs of human beings - or that it, in any way, helps to preserve or sustain the resources of the planet for future generations. If anything, capitalism has become the medium where what is worst in us is magnified and given legitimacy - materialism, greed, indifference to the suffering of others, deceitfulness and hubris - while diminishing the importance of justice, benevolence and environmental stewardship. Hopefully, Piketty's book will be a wake-up call - not a call to fix capitalism, but to overcome it. The fact is that even if a tax on wealth could somehow reconcile the logical contradiction within capitalism, it will do nothing to prevent corporations from their "race to exploit what is left"
[9]; it will not stop them from moving us closer to ecological disaster by extracting oil from bituminous sands or minerals from impoverished third world countries; it will not deter the Wall Street mega banks like Goldman Sachs, the "vampire squid wrapped around the face of humanity" (to borrow Matt Taibbi's startling and vivid description) from sucking the life out of national economies; it will not impede the chemical industry from polluting the environment and using whole populations as unwitting research objects for profit; it will not avert the continuing dissolution of democracy by the superrich Koch brothers . . . and on and on.
Notwithstanding all that has been said, it is still conceivable that we could reverse our present "conditioning" by thinking and acting in different ways - by recognizing that, progressively, with the help of others, we could cultivate radically different perspectives and practices (economic and otherwise). But any such effort must assume that we are also acutely aware
of the ubiquity and the powerful force of capitalist propaganda. As Henry Giroux reminds us "dominant power works relentlessly through its major cultural apparatuses to hide, mischaracterize or lampoon resistance, dissent and critically engaged social movements. This is done, in part, by sanitizing public memory and erasing critical knowledge and oppositional struggles from newspapers, radio, television, film and all those cultural institutions that engage in systemic forms of education and memory work."
[10] Above all, the possibility of alternative economic visions, perspectives and practices have to be grounded in the reality that we share a limited world, and that we are and have always been capable of creating an economic system and public policies that preserve the health and well-being of the planet and all of the creatures that inhabit it.
NOTES:
1. Chrystia Freeland,
Plutocrats, The Rise of the New Global Super-Rich and the Fall of Everyone Else. Anchor Canada 2012. p. xvi. Freeland is likely drawing from Churchill's oft-quoted conclusion that "Democracy is the worst form of government, except for all the others."
2. Karl Polanyi,
The Great Transformation, The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, Beacon Press 1957 pp. 45-58
3. John Locke, "The Second Treatise of Government", in
Princeton Readings in Political Thought, edited by Mitchell Cohen and Nicole Fermon. Princeton University Press, 1996. pp. 243-4
4. See Howard Zinn,
A People's History of the United States, Harper Perennial Modern Classics 2005. pp. 73-75
5. Ronald Wright,
What is America: A Short History of the New World Order, Vintage Canada, 2009. p. 116
6. To really understand the tension within Smith's thought it is helpful to read both
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations and
The Theory of Moral Sentiments.
7. Adam Smith,
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations Book III, Chapter IV.
8. You can find Ayn Rand's and Nathaniel Branden's
The virtue of Selfishness: A New Concept of Egoism.
9. See Michael Klare's
The Race for What's Left: The Global Scramble for the World's Last Resources, Picador, 2012
10. Henry Giroux, "
Hope in the Age of Looming Authoritarianism," Truthout.
Copyright, Truthout. May not be reprinted without
permission.